An Important Point About Increasing Returns
Today: W. Brian Arthur, my perspective on increasing and diminishing returns, industrial policy, Singapore πΈπ¬
The Agenda π
The life and works of W. Brian Arthur
A frequent mistake regarding increasing returns
A few additional ideas on capitalism
A primer on industrial policy
A great article about Singapore
Today, Iβd like to dedicate a brief essay to economist and complexity theorist W. Brian Arthur and his pioneering research on increasing returns.
Hereβs Brianβs short bio: he grew up Catholic in Northern Ireland, did a PhD thesis in operations research at the University of Michigan, worked at McKinsey (I featured his thoughts about the firm in my 11 Notes on McKinsey), specialized in modeling demographics in developing countries, then (at age 37) became the youngest endowed chair holder at Stanford University.
In the second, more consequential part of his career, he contributed to the emergence of the Santa Fe Institute, now the most renowned research organization in the world when it comes to complexity theory.
I briefly met Brian when visiting my friends at CASBS in Palo Alto back in February; he kindly offered to meet for lunch but alas we couldnβt find a mutually convenient date, and a few days later I was back on a plane to Europe. Now, with the pandemic and all, I donβt know when Iβll be back in California or if Iβll have the opportunity again π’
Brian has become a well-known figure in the tech world. If his name sounds familiar, itβs likely youβve discovered him through one the following channels:
Maybe youβre interested in complexity theory in terms of the history of science and youβve read M. Mitchell Waldropβs Complexity(which features Brian prominentlyβin 1992).
Maybe youβre a long-time admirer of complexity economics and youβve read Brianβs academic writings on the matter, such as Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy (1994).
Most likely youβve read Brianβs seminal 1996 article Increasing Returns and the New World of Business in Harvard Business Review (hereβs the background story).
Or, more recently, you could have listened to Brianβs discussion with Sonal Chokshi and Marc Andreessen on the a16z podcast (or read one of Brianβs articles in McKinsey Quarterly).
As for me, I first discovered the 1996 article through Bill Gurley (2014), then bought Brianβs books as well as Waldropβs, then stumbled upon articles and podcasts published more recently.
So, what about todayβs βImportant Pointβ? Many people who read the article in HBR come out of the experience having quite the binary view of the economy:
On one hand thereβs the old industrial economy, that of the age of the automobile and mass production, and itβs marked by diminishing returns to scale.
On the other hand, thereβs the new digital economy, that of ubiquitous computing and networks, and itβs all about increasing returns (or, as the Bible puts it, βTo them that hath shall be givenβ).
However, thatβs too simplistic, and Iβve realized thereβs a different way of telling that story. It requires focusing on the various stages of development in both techno-economic paradigms:
Fordist-Age companies seem subject to diminishing returns, but thatβs because those that are still around these days have reached an advanced life stage and as a result are nearing exhaustion.
Meanwhile, todayβs tech companies strike us as being driven by increasing returns because for most of them, itβs still Day One. Theyβre still in their infancy!
Indeed, the whole point of capitalism is the pursuit of increasing returns. And the fact that the Industrial Revolution and the following technological revolutions have all been such a boon for capitalism is because each contributed better ways of generating increasing returns and arriving at an ever larger scale.
Corporate giants in the age of the automobile and mass production grew larger than those in the age of steel and heavy engineering, which themselves had grown larger than those in the age of steam and railways. And today, we already realize that the largest tech companies will be larger than the manufacturing giants that dominated the global economy in the 20th century.
A few additional ideas to illustrate that point:
When large players reach the stage where returns start to diminish rather than increase, thatβs when youβd expect new entrants to be able to seize the opportunity to tackle incumbents. But thatβs not what happens, for a very simple reason: returns that start to diminish are correlated with having a high level of defensibility. As an example, returns stopped increasing a long time ago in the car industry, still who would be crazy enough to launch a new car manufacturer (assuming, that is, that youβre not being lifted up by technological change in batteries)?
In his podcast conversation with Brian, Marc Andreessen quotes Peter Thiel and makes the case that βif you donβt have increasing returns, youβre on a long-term downward slide to commodityβ. If youβve read Walter Kiechelβs The Lords of Strategy (highly recommended!), this is precisely where strategy starts to become relevant. In the presence of increasing returns, itβs anything goes, because you want to detach and race ahead so as to secure lock-in. But when returns eventually start to diminish, thatβs when you need to focus on strategy.
CEOs from the old paradigm seem clueless in the age of computing and networks (take John Sculley, the former CEO of PepsiCo, almost leading Apple into the ground). But thatβs because they only know the late stage: their main skill as a corporate CEO is about managing a large organization cursed with diminishing returns to scale. So when you put them in charge of a smaller/younger company that still enjoys increasing returns, things go wrong quickly.
In a Stratechery update last year, Ben Thompson observed that βsilicon-based chips have similar characteristics [as software]; there are massive up-front costs to develop and build a working chip, but once built additional chips can be manufactured for basically nothingβ. I found this observation odd at the time, and I still do, because for me building silicon chips is a manufacturing business, and the economics pointed out by Ben are characteristics of manufacturing...in its early stages of development.
If only to reinforce the point, doesnβt it strike you that all of todayβs tech giants are reaching the point where returns are finally starting to diminish? See Apple and its problems with the App Store (and manufacturing in China!); Amazon failing to manage trust on its marketplace, notably because of fraud in user-generated reviews and the bad quality of products sold; Google being unable to preserve its culture and finally becoming an βevilβ company; and Facebook, well, being vilified for the divisive impact of their core product.
So hereβs my βImportant Pointβ: donβt misread Brianβs work and think that weβre living in a completely different world now. Itβs something else: because itβs still early in the Entrepreneurial Age, most dominant companies today are enjoying increasing returns similar to (even better than) those that leading car manufacturers enjoyed in the first half of the 20th century. This is why they succeed at doing capitalism, but this doesnβt mean that it will last foreverβor that increasing returns are a feature thatβs perennially inherent to the Entrepreneurial Age.
Also (as Iβm re-reading Brianβs article and am again struck by his harsh criticism of legacy economists), remember Mary OβSullivanβs illuminating observation:
If you want to understand capitalism, talk to capitalists, not economists.
Indeed, as revealed by Fernand Braudel, capitalists, unlike economists, have always known itβs all about increasing returnsβlong before the rise of computing and networks. And in the words of Brian himself:
Mechanisms of increasing returns exist alongside those of diminishing returns in all industries.
What do you think?
You might have read about Dominic Cummings, a senior advisor to Britainβs Boris Johnson, wanting to build trillion-dollar tech companies in the UK (and being willing to botch Brexit negotiations in the process). At the same time, Macron is schmoozing tech entrepreneurs in Paris, promising them billions of euros to be allocated βartificial intelligence, cybersecurity and quantum computingβ π€
And so I thought I would again highlight what industrial policy is all about. Hereβs a bullet-point primer:
Industrial policy should be designed differently if youβre a leader or a follower. A leader is the most advanced in terms of economic development and is at the frontier from a technology perspective. Being a follower means trying to catch up to that.
A country thatβs the leader (like the US these days) should implement a policy thatβs all about waste, trials and errors, and cutting-edge technology. It only helps to welcome immigrants (both high-skilled and low-skilled).
A follower, on the other hand, should be focused on catching up. That requires active management of the workforce (keep workers where they are, and make it rewarding), supporting emerging champions with proven increasing returns, and financial repression.
A frequent mistake is being a follower and implementing an industrial policy thatβs only fit for a leader. Thatβs what both Cummings and Macron have in mind, with their obsession over basic research and high tech. (Meanwhile the UK let ARM slip away, sold to Nvidia.)
In both cases (leading and following), the government needs to provide a direction, usually using the terms of waging a war. If youβre the leader, it might be an actual war (as with WWII, which gave birth to Silicon Valley). If youβre a follower, itβs simpler: just wage a war against under-developmentβlike Taiwan, South Korea, and Mainland China successfully did in the second half of the 20th century!
But this requires something painful for countries like France and the UK: admitting that theyβre lagging behind from an economic development perspective. I wrote about this here: Europe Is a Developing Economy.
πΈπ¬ An excellent article about Singapore succeeding as a follower made the rounds recently (I discovered it in Margins). I wrote about languages in Singapore in a previous edition of this newsletter, but this really explores all the dimensions of what a successful industrial policy is all about: The True Story of Lee Kuan Yewβs Singapore (Haonan Li & Victor Yaw, Palladium, August 2020).
If youβve been forwarded this paid edition of European Straits, you should subscribe so as not to miss the next ones.
From Normandy, France π«π·
Nicolas